Monday, February 14, 2022

STATE ROLE IN BUSINESS

Government role in business has always been controversial, often inefficient and even illiberal. Communism was the most problematic. Postwar experiments in liberal European countries with state planning and state-owned enterprises became largely discredited by the 1980s. For example, industries at the “commanding heights” of the British economy were nationalized in the late 1940s but that experiment was reversed by privatization under Margaret Thatcher’s government.

There were exceptional results with state enterprise, such as in Singapore where state-owned enterprises became a more efficient sector than the local private sector (dominated by property and trading enterprises). Even so, Singapore emulated Thatcher’s privatization to some extent, to bring in private-sector efficiencies and capital. Other government roles had some success, such as Japan’s Ministry of International Trade and Industry coordination of national industries.

Free societies are today demanding more elaborate control of business, if not by state ownership then other state interventions. The state is expected to solve complex needs for control of enterprise, as political leaders are under pressure from their constituencies to resolve issues with capitalism –including interventions that are not necessarily within the power of political elites or even wise such as a role in labor relations, finance and banking, and lately the pandemic lockdowns and safety protocols for industry and education. Under intense political pressures, democratic leaders are intervening in their businesses, expected to resolve modern problems ranging from global warming, technology monopolization and data abuse, banking and financial stability, social responsibility of private enterprises for diversity, eliminating poverty, etc.

State ownership is only one means of government intervention, and generally declining. Much state ownership constitutes minority interests, or by holding companies, sovereign wealth and pension funds, or other professional owners and managers. Today, governments mostly intervene in other ways.

President Trump was critical of globalization and adopted populist policies, including trade wars with China and even American allies. President Biden engages in protectionism, requiring domestic suppliers and union labor, and general policy priorities to return wealth and power to American workers. Biden has engaged his administration in resolving supply-chain problems, bailing out businesses, promulgating pandemic safety policies in businesses, and many other interventions. Even China is tinkering with its communist model to achieve “common prosperity” and also tame its free-wheeling entrepreneurs and compel political obedience.

America never relied on state ownership of enterprises as much as Europe and East Asia. Yet today America has broadened the range of national security concerns where government intervention is justified, notably energy industries. Technology export controls, punitive sanctions on foreign countries’ trade and finance, and screening foreign investment are increasingly frequent options. Subsidies are devised for more R&D and capital spending, such as Biden’s $52 billion program to support semiconductor production.

The primacy of shareholder wealth maximization –in vogue from at least the 1970s, is finally being questioned, as firms are expected to raise their concern for other stakeholders – consumers, employees, the environment, and even respect for competition and healthy markets including helping smaller firms. Governments have promulgated “ESG” investment codes to score firms’ wider responsibility for energy efficiency, worker safety, board independence, etc.

Negative impact of state intervention is pervasive, but more subtly includes both the state and its firms’ need to balance conflicting interests. For example, fossil-fuel firms must protect jobs and prosperity in their community (and long-term profits), and so may avoid any divestment needed to protect the environment. Trade embargos against China about human rights blocks cheaper imports. Businesses anyway cannot make these judgements, which are government decisions. Such decisions increase costs and impair open competition. If businesses attempt any role, they find more need for political involvement, including even corruption. 

Government investment, through ownership or simply subsidies, has always been a means to direct national resources toward desired industry. It seems illogical to engage in industrial policy for ideological reasons, but some countries have been more encumbered by political or bureaucratic pressures and may invest unwisely. Although the record in America has been less propitious at “picking winners”, than for example East Asia, the US government has played a crucial role in creating so much of American industry in internet, biotechnology, and many of the other strong industries of today. Now it invests in AI, quantum computing, medical science.

Where a need for industrial policies is obvious, such as energy industries in the age of global warming, certainly the US government is obligated to play a role. During the pandemic governments focused their investment to enhance domestic capacity. France’s “2030” plan earmarks expenditures of 160bn euros over five years in medicines, small nuclear reactors, but also cultural investments. With respect to the last mentioned state initiative, grand dreams are obviously a government proclivity.

Competition between governments to make their industries international “winners” may simply result in an “industrial policy arms race” –competitive government subsidies. Governments are also notoriously mercurial, wanting not only to create new national champions but also not letting losers fail.

A frequent tendency of industrial and competition policy is to police private sector behavior that may have socioeconomic impact, such as antitrust, improper pricing or other harm to consumer welfare. In China, children have been prohibited from playing video games more than three times per week, it being a distraction from studies. Antitrust concerns are broadening to the kind of concerns reflected in the way companies like Facebook compete, including the “killer acquisition” to takeover Instagram to prevent that enterprise becoming a competitor with Facebook. Regulators such as the Fair Trade Commission look to long-range and global competitive outcomes in business decisions.  

Thus, bureaucracy and politics are rising in their impact on business. In China the state holds the power in business interventions, while in Europe or the USA the courts and legislatures are preeminent.  In any case, interventions are increasingly prevalent in the modern world. The result is more bureaucracy and “red tape”; and once new regulators are created and funded, politics and bureaucratic inertia stymie efforts to defund.